Friday, January 17, 2014

Repost - Reliability and Conflict in California Water by Tom Stroshane

Spillway News Winter 2002

Reliability and Conflict in California Water, Part 1Water Under the Bridge?
Reliability and Conflict in
California Water, Part 1
By Tim Stroshane
Water observers of yesteryear—like Henry Holsinger of
the California Water Project Authority and water lawyer
Walter M. Gleason—worried that the Central Valley Project
(CVP), and later the State Water Project (SWP), would cause
legal havoc, even though these big projects were to expand
California’s reliable water supply. They saw, even before
construction of the CVP and SWP, the potential for constitutional,
ecological, and economic controversies, and that
resolving them would be highly political. 
“Water rights are social policy in times of shortage,” says
water lawyer Scott Slater.1 
To understand where California water politics is going, it
helps to step back to explain California water through the
trend of its human institutions. Some might consider this to
be “water under the bridge,” yesterday’s news becoming
today’s fish wrap. So be it. 
Institutions Californians create to govern water allocation,
management, and stewardship define and structure the
state’s water future.2 Two such institutions are the legal
doctrines of riparian and appropriative rights. They historically
shape two central concerns of California water policy:
reliability and conflict. 
Water supply reliability receded as developed supplies
expanded, from the standpoint of water and environmental
law. As supplies expanded and overreached the carrying
capacity of California’s rivers and streams, legal conflict
flourished. Only institutional changes wrought by modern
environmentalism, like the federal Clean Water Act, made
possible the reality that Californians could control their water
institutions and in the process dream of living within their
hydraulic and hydrological means. 
Violent Changes, Utopian Hopes 
Decades before the remarkable spate of environmental
legislation of the 1960s and 1970s, government officials still
needed to know what impacts, consequences, or “critical
paths” of actions would follow from choosing to build
gargantuan water projects. Then, as now, they hired scientists,
economists, engineers, and lawyers to do studies. 
The U.S. Bureau of Reclamation undertook its “Central
Valley Project Studies,” a series of nearly 30 studies dealing
with various technical, legal, economic, financial, and
ecological issues that were posed by the prospect of actually
constructing and operating the Central Valley Project. The
CVP studies were directed by a University of Chicago
geographer named Harlan Barrows. 
In the fall of 1942, A.D. Edmonston, then acting director
of the California Water Project Authority (CWPA), wrote to
Dr. Barrows to recommend two questions that were in all
likelihood crafted by Henry Holsinger, an associate lawyer
with the CWPA: 
“Problem No. 25: Is there necessity for a comprehensive
adjudication of rights to the use of water on streams the
natural regimen of which will be altered by operation of the
[Central Valley Project]? 
“Problem No. 26: If there is need for such comprehensive
adjudication, can the same be accomplished under
existing law, and if not, what enabling legislation is necessary?” 
Through Thanksgiving and early December 1942,
Holsinger fashioned a memorandum arguing the Bureau
should include these two problems in the CVP studies. Even
today, it is a lucid statement of how property rights in water
dictate operations and, indeed, the fundamental design of the
Central Valley Project (CVP).3 
The memo apparently persuaded Barrows in Chicago,
who in turn recommended including the legal problems to
Bureau Commissioner John C. Page in Washington, DC, in
early 1943. 
“Never in the history of the State has there been an
instance where a water conservation project was put in
operation which involved such violent and extensive
changes in the regimen of any stream,” a somber Holsinger
wrote. These changes, he suggested, were to be inserted into
a property regime whose “history is one of continuous
conflict and the resolution thereof,” a history that was hardly
finished.4 
“The enormous expense of litigation over water rights,”
continued Holsinger, “has often been deplored, involving time consuming, expensive and all too frequently fruitless [lawsuits]; fruitless because decrees rendered were piecemeal
and for that reason unenforcible [sic] and because other
interests on the stream, although intimately involved[,] were
not made parties or because of technical defects” in the cases
themselves. 
Holsinger sought to shatter any naive optimism in the
Bureau’s leadership about the CVP’s legal status in California.

“It would be pleasant to anticipate that all such difficulties
are now at an end and that this vast project, notwithstanding
its radical alteration of stream regimen, will be
peaceably accepted by those affected thereby without
controversy, without objection, and without resorting to
litigation. However, attention to realities should convince
any reasonable mind that any such anticipation is utopian
and not reasonably possible of fulfillment.”5 
Riparian Rights 
Such hopes were utopian not only because of human
frailties such as greed. Utopian hopes for the Central Valley
Project to provide ample water supplies to CVP contractors
were likely to founder on conflicts between riparian and
appropriative doctrines coexisting in an arid region, feared
Holsinger. 
In California, tensions between riparian and appropriative
right holders often erupted into litigation, going back to
the early days of statehood. Riparian rights entail the right to
use water as a result of owning property adjacent to a natural
stream or lake. They give the owner a right to reasonable,
beneficial use of water on that property.6 Riparian doctrine
was brought to California when the new state in 1850
adopted English common law for its own legal system. 
Riparian rights establish a clear connection of waters
flowing in a stream to the land adjacent where the riparian
owner may use the water. In effect, they respect and codify
an ecological—as well as economic—relationship between
human use of both water and land. 
Of course riparian rights may also benefit capitalist
production and reproduction (e.g., home life, domestic use).
But these rights are still correlative among all riparian
owners along a stream; each owner has a share of stream.  
The more appropriators on a stream,
the more competition in dry years, and
the less reliable are the more junior rights
to water supply obtained through the
state’s appropriative permit process—
including those of the CVP and SWP.

flows, and each must ensure flows of adequate quantity and
quality to avoid injury to downstream riparians. Riparian
right holders participate in a hydraulic commons 
.
Historically, riparian rights were also associated with land
monopoly.7 The largest whipping boy of early California land
monopoly was Miller and Lux, the great cattle baronage of
central California and the San Joaquin Valley.8 Miller and
Lux was a major cattle and beef marketing corporation
whose empire reached from southern Oregon and northern
Nevada to San Francisco and the northern San Joaquin
Valley.9 Miller and Lux did much to shape California’s water
law and jurisprudence. Its hydro-legacy was achieved largely
through court case precedents—including establishment of
riparian priorities over those of appropriators—but the
corporation also thoroughly remade much of central
California’s land and waterscapes to benefit its beef production
and water sales.10 
“Riparianism pressed to the limits of its logic,” the U.S.
Supreme Court wrote in Gerlach v. United States case in
June 1950, “enabled one to play dog-in-the-manger...[in
which one] could enforce by injunction his bare technical
right to have the natural flow of the stream, even if he was
getting no substantial benefit from it.”11 
In 1928 California voters amended their state constitution
to ensure the criterion of reasonable beneficial use would
govern all water uses (including riparians) in perpetuity,

making “dog-in-the-manger” games with water impossible
today.12 Yet reasonable use also makes water supplies less
reliable and more subject to litigation and political conflict.
After all, what’s reasonable? 
Appropriation’s Elusive Surplus 
In California, the appropriative doctrine is laid atop the
riparian doctrine’s allocations in the state’s watersheds. Land
owners along streams typically have riparian rights. To the extent their rights do not require all the flows of a river or stream, then, California’s hydro-legal minds reason, there is therefore a surplus. 
“All waters in excess of the reasonable and beneficial
needs of lawful users, including riparians, are considered
unappropriated waters and are available for beneficial use,”
write water lawyers Arthur Littleworth and Eric Garner.
Exercise of this logic was pivotal to building California’s
numerous water projects, including the CVP and SWP.13 
Appropriative rights were invented by Gold Rush miners
staking claims for mines on public lands where they could
claim no riparian rights
(since the U.S. Government owned
the land they mined). Appropriative rights involve the right
to divert and use a specific quantity of water for reasonable,
beneficial use in a specific location.
Littleworth and Garner
note that these rights involve a “first-in-time, first-in-right”
principle. The first individual on a stream to divert and use
water beneficially and reasonably has an appropriative right
superior to all those who come after to that stream.14 Only
appropriators have their rights quantified.
Since 1914,
appropriators apply to the State for permits to appropriate
water.15 
Appropriative rights sunder ecological relationships of
water to land. They make it possible to mobilize water
beyond mere watershed or place, to liberate water from
constraints of native gravity by economic and technological
means, and to incorporate it into circuits of modern capitalist
production and urban life. The actual place of use of the
water may in California be hundreds of miles from their
origin in the stream as with the CVP and SWP. 
As water becomes property treated as a set of investment backed
expectations for future income and profit, big public
water projects face the collision of property rights with
ecological reality in times of drought. 
“When the amount of water available is insufficient to
meet the needs of all appropriators, traditional case law holds
that junior appropriators can be prevented from exercising
their rights until the water rights of senior appropriators are
satisfied,
write Littleworth and Garner. “However, this rule
seems impractical today, since the cities and water districts
providing urban water supplies generally hold appropriative
rights. Because it is generally unrealistic to terminate such
uses completely, courts can be seen to be moving way from a
strict application of the first-in-time doctrine in order to
protect established uses.”16 
The pecking order of appropriative priorities seems
arbitrary to some when droughts occur—especially when any
of today’s water users get pecked. Littleworth, for one, looks
forward to a time in California when a doctrine of “equitable
apportionment” would supplant water right priorities,
replacing them with a commons of appropriative rights
holders. 
Yet appropriative rights have also been able instruments
of land monopolists like James Ben Ali Haggin, Miller and
Lux’s cattle rival of the 19th Century in Kern County. The
contemporary Kern County Land Company descends from
Haggin’s empire. Clearly, routes to land baronage in California
run through either type of water right. Strategies to
address unequal political and economic power in living
watersheds through equitable apportionment, however, are
not the strong suit of this as-yet emerging doctrine.17 
Through wet years, riparian and appropriative doctrines
co-exist, though uneasily. Right holders know that next year
could bring dry conditions and conflict. The more appropriators
on a stream, the more competition for water in dry years,
and the less reliable are the more junior rights to water
supply obtained through the state’s appropriative permit
process—including those of the CVP and SWP.18 
When the state and federal governments planned the big
water projects, they knew they would have to appropriate
waters then believed to be surplus in the state’s major
watersheds. Henry Holsinger, in his lawyerly way, doubted a
surplus in the Sacramento Valley could be truly known: “If
assumptions are made [about the definition of water rights on
the Sacramento], someone must take the risk of the accuracy
thereof...but in the final analysis, they consist wholely [sic]
and entirely in assumptions 
“Any and all investigations [into quantifying water
rights] are evidentiary merely,” and without any legal force,
he wrote in 1942.19
 
Could we ask Henry Holsinger today, he might offer numbers pulled from the air as of similar legal heft in the CVP’s position on the Sacramento, and of the
SWP on the Feather River. 
Miller and Lux and Monopoly 
In early 1939, the Bureau of Reclamation acquired from
notorious land monopolist Miller and Lux all the nonriparian
water rights—and agreed to store and replace (but
not own) riparian water rights—to the San Joaquin River. 
Miller and Lux’s rights on the San Joaquin River comprised
nearly the entire flow of that river and were jealously
held by several company subsidiaries.20
 
Water covered by the Bureau’s acquisition would be impounded by a new dam
constructed by the Bureau at Friant where the river arrives at
the edge of the San Joaquin Valley floor.
 
Water at Friant Dam would then be diverted via canals north to Madera and south
to Kern and Tulare county farmers on the east side of the
Valley. River channel flows would all but cease below Friant.21 
This action would cut off water to the subsidiaries’ San
Joaquin riparian swamp and grasslands. The solution was for
the Bureau to provide Miller and Lux’s riparian lands with
replacement water stored at Shasta Dam north of Redding,
released into the Sacramento River for eventual diversion in
amounts of water will be available at the point of diversion
on the Sacramento River, is largely dependent upon the will
of the existing users on the approximately 300 mile intervening
course between the point of diversion and the point of
storage” who could challenge CVP operations for failing in
any way to provide Sacramento River users with flows
sufficient to fulfill their water rights.25 
Only a “comprehensive definition” of all water rights up
and down the Sacramento Valley would make CVP deliveries
truly reliable and protect existing water rights holders at
the same time, wrote Holsinger. If the CVP went ahead, he
observed, San Joaquin Valley agricultural development
would expand on the promise of replacement Sacramento
River irrigation water.
Without legal certainties in place, “to
withdraw that water would cause harm in the San Joaquin
Valley and place the United States in a disastrous predicament.” 
Constitutional issues are at stake in promises made by
the Delta via the Delta Cross Channel and exported from the
Delta by pumps installed at Tracy for lift into the Delta-
Mendota Canal (DMC).
 
The DMC would snake its way
through the San Joaquin Valley
to irrigate lands of the “Exchange
Contractors” (as Miller & Lux’s descendant companies
are known today). these big projects to deliver
water for agricultural and urban development. They
involve both reasonable water use and just compensation for
property taken by the government. 
To export water from one watershed to another
creates future expectations based on today’s investments.
To withdraw or reallocate water breaks promises, most
solemnly made.
Yet to justify the appropriations—continuously and perpetually—the uses to which water is put must always and forever be reasonable.
And what is considered “reasonable” can change, a stance in
water policy that is also reasonable to assume. 
While Holsinger focused his memorandum to Barrows on
riparian right holders along the Sacramento, he likely had in
mind “area of origins” reservations set aside in state law in
the early 1930s as well.
26
 
These laws reserve water in source
areas (for example, rural counties with ample water resources)
for their future needs to prevent “Owens Valley”
scenarios from recurring. They place a theoretical limit on
how much and for how long the CVP and SWP—and even
other major water projects—will be able to take water and
move it far from its origins. 
The point of this is not that comprehensive definition or quantification of water rights should have occurred or should now occur. Rather, Holsinger foresaw that huge capital
investments made for the CVP could be derailed or undermined
by a water right holder insisting on a quantity that
would legally impair the CVP’s contractual delivery commitments,
and usher in perhaps a balkanizing spiral of litigation,
undermining the very investment California and the U.S.
government made to increase the state’s water supply
reliability. His analysis highlights the potential for compensable
property takings by the government should water be
withdrawn. 
In March 1943, Bureau Commissioner John Page
declined to include proposed Problems 25 and 26 in the CVP
studies in a terse message to the new WPA director Edward
Hyatt, despite Barrows’ and Edmonston’s earlier recommendations.
27 
Water Rights and Predatory Government 
In the 1950s, water lawyer Walter Gleason, whose career
in California water law began in the early 1920s and would
last nearly seven decades, saw dangers of unchecked
appropriative rights for the Central Valley and the areas of
origins. 
Gleason saw unquantified riparian rights as exceptionally
vulnerable to ostensibly junior appropriative right holders
moving in for what news media colorfully refer to as a
“water grab.”
Appropriators moving into a watershed
challenge riparians on the grounds that their water usage may
take on or interfere with any water or water rights in Northern
California [is] concerned,” Gleason wrote. But passage
of the 1960 water bond would place the state of California in
position to challenge water users for reasonableness on
behalf of State water contractors (of which the Metropolitan
Water District is the largest). 
With southern California’s insertion into the Central
Valley watersheds of the Sacramento-San Joaquin River
Delta, Gleason maintained that no vested rights in northern
California (which he defined as waters north of the
Tehachapis) are safe from predation by the state running
interference for southern California.
29 
“In the absence of comprehensive adjudication,” wrote
Gleason, “there will be no effective and readily ascertainable
demarcation (i.e., ‘boundary line’) between ‘surplus’ (on the
one side) and ‘non-surplus’ on the other. In the absence of
such an obligatory definition of these two correlatives, there
be unreasonable, or that an unreasonable amount may be
diverted. Protracted litigation then ensued in which an existing
user’s “water duty” had to be established and his or her water
right effectively quantified. 
Gleason believed that the new State Water Project (SWP) would
create opportunities for litigious water grabs on an unprecedented
scale aimed at the north.
. Southern California’s cities would seek
northern California’s “surplus waters” (which Gleason considered
everything above the Tehachapis) in litigious invasion
for water, with assistance from the state of California. 
“Water right-wise [sic],” Gleason wrote on the eve of the
November 1960 election that saw John Kennedy elected
President and the State Water Project bonds narrowly
approved by California voters, “the end result of this new
Water Plan will be exactly the same as if all of Southern
California were to be physically uprooted and set down at
Tracy (i.e., next to Delta).
In short, the length of the aqueduct
between the Tracy Pumping Plant [at the north end of the
California Aqueduct] is immaterial since the South will...be
sitting next to the Delta with a right to receive water out of
the Delta (through its ‘water contract’ with the State). 
“A direct consequence of this new ‘hydrology’,” he
continued, “is that for the first time in history the South will
become directly and legally interested in the water resources
of the Central Valley and the water rights (existing and
prospective) in connection therewith.”28 California’s regions
would be bound together as never before, and Gleason
worried that technological prowess would outrun legal
insight into the new system. 
Prior to the State Water Project, Southern California
“might as well be in Mexico insofar as any present ability to
Governor Edmund G. “Pat” Brown on the stump for
the State Water Project in Santa Clara County.
can be no effective (i.e., automatic) controls to delimit this
‘export’ of water [from the North to the South]. When this ‘hard
reality’ is coupled with the indisputable fact that it will be
directly to the mutual interest of both the State and the South to
maintain this ‘export flow to the South’ as continuously and on as
large a scale as possible,
the inevitability of direct and serious
conflict between these vested water rights of the North and these
‘export allocations’ is, I believe, patent.”
30 
With the State Water Project (SWP), the state of California
became a water developer as well as a water regulator.
The state and federal projects appropriated the two largest blocs of allegedly surplus waters in
California.31 
In its quest to bring reliability to California’s future water
supply, the state’s conflict of interest would limit its capacity
to protect Californians and their watersheds from what
Manteca-area farmer and south Delta water official Alex
Hildebrand refers to as “the predatory nature of government.

32
The Quality of Delta Water 
Water lawyers, like most of us, do not make good
soothsayers. Not only do events conspire to drive history
from its ruts, but human institutions also undergo radical
shifts in social, economic, and even ecological priorities. The
rise of environmentalism in the 1960s punctuated the
prerogatives of appropriative water rights as a property
institution. 
Once the big projects were completed, neither a bareknuckled
southern California appropriative water grab of the kind envisioned by Walter Gleason, nor a paralyzing avalanche of Sacramento Valley riparian “dog-in-the-manger”
litigation feared by Henry Holsinger occurred. 
But by the 1970s, salinization of Delta freshwater
channels—a common pool from which Delta riparian land
owners draw their irrigation water
—made clear that storage
and diversions of the big projects exceeded the waters
available from Central Valley watersheds. Flows left in Delta
streams were too low to push back the tidal salt waters of
San Francisco Bay, harming Delta farmers holding riparian
water rights. 
The struggle over Delta water quality began in the 1920s
when rice growers began diverting irrigation water from the
Sacramento River during dry years. But as historians W.
Turrentine Jackson and Alan Paterson correctly observed in
necessary only to protect water rights in the Delta against
impairment by the big projects. But Racanelli corrected the
Board, saying that the Clean Water Act requires that “beneficial
uses” are what need protection from water quality
regulations, not water rights. 
The Board’s second error lay in assuming that only the
state and federal projects were accountable for rectifying
water quality problems in the Delta.
As a result, “the Board
erroneously based its water quality objectives upon the
unjustified premise that upstream users retained unlimited
access to upstream waters while the projects and Delta
parties were entitled only to share the remaining water
flows.
”35 
Judge Racanelli echoed Holsinger and Gleason’s observations
that a comprehensive adjudication of Sacramento
Valley water rights, however desirable, was not practical.36 
But the genius of Racanelli’s opinion lay in his insistence
that “the trial court’s basic premise—that water quality
protection hinges on ownership of water rights—is
faulty....[T]he Board’s authority in setting water quality
standards is not limited to the protection of water rights, but
extends to the protection of all beneficial uses from degradation
of water quality, even if the resulting water quality
exceeds that provided by water rights,” he wrote.37 
In other words, the goal of water quality standards is to
protect the use value of water, not water’s exchange value as
a property right, commodity, and income source. 
State Board Horror 
State and federal water contractors (those entities
contracting for water service from the CVP and SWP in the
San Joaquin Valley and in Southern California) argued also
that the Board failed to protect the contractors’ rights to use
Delta water for a dependable water supply, claiming to do
otherwise was a compensable property taking under Article 5
of the U.S. Constitution and an impairment of their contract
rights. 
Racanelli affirmed the trial court’s opinion that no
property taking had occurred because “the federal contractors
have no water rights of their own but are subject to the
limitations of the permits held by the CVP,” which are
appropriative water rights, subject to the Board’s reserved
jurisdiction, permit terms, and the state constitution’s
prohibitions on unreasonable water use.
38
 
Moreover, the contracts themselves limit both state and federal projects’
liability for deliveries during droughts. “Logically,” wrote
Racanelli, “neither the project nor the contractors could have
any reasonable expectation of certainty that the agreed
quantity of water will be delivered.”
39 
Judge Racanelli tacitly acknowledged what only environmentalists
knew to be true at the time, that Central Valley
rivers were over-appropriated by the CVP and SWP; water
exports dreamed of in the 1957 California Water Plan could
never be realized. The big projects starved important
fisheries and Delta agriculture of fresh water to which both
were entitled. 
The Racanelli decision (sometimes called the Delta Water Cases) ultimately became the intellectual prism through which appropriative, riparian, and instream water uses are now viewed, as well as the legal foundation on which the
CalFED Bay-Delta Program edifice has been erected so,
well, unreliably. 
Part 2 to come: Bay-Delta Hearings, the 1995 WQCP,
and the river agreements. 
NOTES 
1. Scott Slater, attorney with Hatch & Parent, Santa Barbara,
from public comments at “Water Rights, Water Wrongs:
Learning from the Past, Looking to the Future,” conference
sponsored by the San Francisco Estuary Institute, Oakland,
CA, 2 November 1999.
 
2. My guiding light for this approach is economic historian
Karl Polanyi, author of The Great Transformation: The
Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, Boston, MA:
Beacon Press, 1944, 1957, p. 4.
 
3. Holsinger would go on to become chief legal counsel of
the California Division of Water Rights in the late 1940s and
1950s, a predecessor agency of the State Water Resources
Control Board.
 
4. Henry Holsinger, “Necessity for Comprehensive Adjudication
of Water Rights on the Sacramento and San Joaquin
Rivers in Aid of the Central Valley Project,” memorandum
manuscript dated 10 December 1942, p. 2. Hereafter,
Holsinger, “Necessity.”
 
5. “Necessity,” ibid. 
6. Arthur Littleworth and Eric Garner, California Water, Point
Arena, CA: Solano Press Books, 1995, p. 29. Of riparian
water rights they add, “A riparian right is not gained by use,
nor generally lost by disuse, but is part and parcel of the
land.” Ibid.
 
7. See M. Catherine Miller, Flooding the Courtroom: Law and
Water in the Far West, Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska
Press, 1993; and David Igler, Industrial Cowboys: Miller and
Lux and the Transformation of the Far West, 1850 to 1920,
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 2001.
 
8. According to Igler, ibid., Miller and Lux ranches encompassed
over half a million acres of land in four major areas of
California: the Kern River delta northwest of Bakersfield (near
rival Haggin’s cattle ranches), lands along the San Joaquin
River from Mendota almost to the Stanislaus County line,
major holdings around Gilroy, and Lux’s Buri Buri ranch at the
north end of the San Francisco Peninsula.
 
9. California Department of Public Works, Feasibility of
Acquiring the Central Valley Project, March 1952, pp. 57-60
. 
10. For that history, see M. Catherine Miller, Flooding the
Courtrooms, op. cit., note 8 above. Miller and Lux achieved
this status through its vast ranches’ fencing enclosures
(contributing greatly to populist sentiment in early California),
industrialization of cattle raising, racial segmentation of
industrial labor markets, marshaling of capital to finance and
construct a complex latticework of canals diverting the waters
of the San Joaquin and Kern rivers onto its swamp and
grasslands. See Igler, op. cit., note 9 above.
 
11. Gerlach et al v. United States, June 1950, manuscript
from Harry Barnes’ files at the Water Resources Center
Archive, University of California, Berkeley, Barnes file number
179-2, p. 17. Also cited as 76 F.Supp. 87.
 
12. California Constitution, Article X, Section 2. 
13. Littleworth and Garner, op. cit., note 6, p. 39. “Water that
is diverted pursuant to an appropriative right may be used on
or in connection with lands away from streams or outside a
watershed, as well as on lands contiguous to streams.
However, this use may be governed by other provisions such
as area-of-origin limitations and the needs of fish and wildlife,
which are now beneficial uses.” Most hydro-legal thinkers in
the 1940s and 1950s, however, had a blind spot for the
needs of fish and wildlife, their implicit grasp of reasonable
and beneficial uses not extending to all of God’s creations,
but only those most useful in capitalist production and urban
development.
 
14. Ibid. Under prior appropriation, water in a stream is not
treated like a commons, as it is under riparian doctrine.
 
15. CVP and SWP water contractors, however, possess
neither riparian nor appropriative rights; they possess
contracts for water service from the big projects, both of
which are the state’s largest water appropriators.
 
16. Littleworth and Garner, op. cit., note 6, p. 39. 
17. Arthur Littleworth, “The Common Law of the Future,”
public remarks at “Water Rights, Water Wrongs,” Oakland,
CA, 2 November 1999. Equitable apportionment was dealt a
severe blow by the California Supreme Court in City of
Barstow v. Mojave Water Agency, California Supreme Court,
S071728. See also “Don’t Tread on Mojave,” SPILLWAY
v1n1, Fall 2000, pp. 2-3.
 
18. The permit system has been in effect since 1914.
Holders of rights that predate the permit system are referred
to as “pre-1914” rights and have priority over rights holders
with post-1914 appropriative permits.
 
19. Holsinger, “Necessity,” op. cit., note 4, p. 16. 
20. Their modern-day descendants include the Columbia
Canal Company, the Firebaugh Canal Company, San Luis
Water District, and Gravelly Ford Canal Company.
 
21. Completion and operation of Friant Dam would ultimately
kill off the spring run chinook salmon of the San Joaquin
River by the mid-1950s, despite meager efforts by committed
fish and game biologists to save this variety of salmon. See
George Warner, “Remember the San Joaquin,” in Alan Lufkin,
ed., California’s Salmon and Steelhead: The Struggle to
Restore an Imperiled Resource, Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press, 1991, pp. 61-69.
 
22. Holsinger, “Necessity,” op. cit., note 4, p. 5. 
23. Ibid., p. 5, 15. 24. 
24. California Department of Public Works, op. cit., note 9,
Appendix G, pp. 221-239. See Article 12(a) of the Purchase
Agreement and Article 7 of the Exchange Agreement between
Miller and Lux, Inc., and the United States Bureau of
Reclamation, July 1939. If replacement water the Bureau
provided the Exchange Contractors via the Delta-Mendota
Canal fell to less than 72 percent of what their entitlement,
then the Exchange Agreement requires the Bureau to make
up the deficiency (back up to 72 percent of the Purchase
Agreement delivery schedule) by releasing water from Friant
Dam for use by the Exchange Contractors. The Contractors
protect this exchange right by having retained their riparian
rights as allowed under the Purchase Agreement.
 
25. Holsinger, “Necessity,” op. cit., note 4, p. 8. 
26. California Water Code Section 10505 and Sections
11460-11463.
 
27. Letter of John C. Page, Commissioner of U.S. Bureau of
Reclamation, to Edward S. Hyatt, Directory of the California
Water Project Authority, 10 March 1943.
 
28. California Senate Interim Committee on Water Projects,
Senator Stephen P. Teale, Chairman, Opinion of Attorney
Walter M. Gleason Regarding Various Legal Aspects of
Burns-Porter Act (SB 1106) (Proposition One), October 28,
1960, p. 15.
 
29. From this perspective, the CalFED “Framework for
Decision” proposal for a “water quality exchange” by the
Metropolitan Water District of Southern California and the
Friant Water Users Authority (on the San Joaquin River) both
is hardly surprising, and takes on new meaning. More than
merely pragmatic and practical, proposed CalFED water
quality exchanges effectively reverse water right priorities
without acts by the state Legislature or decisions by state
courts or the State Water Resources Control Board. In that
sense, CalFED’s plans are beyond politics, beyond law. See
CalFED Bay-Delta Program, “Framework for Action,” June 9,
2000; and Tim Stroshane, “Reframing CalFED,” SPILLWAY

30. Gleason, op. cit., note 28, p. 21. 
31. State Water Resources Control Board, Final Environmental
Impact Report for Implementation of the 1995 Bay/
Delta Water Quality Control Plan, Volume 1, November 1999,
p. III-5, and Table III-5, p. III-24. 
32. Alex Hildebrand, personal communication, Manteca,
California, 10 December 1999. 
33. W. Turrentine Jackson and Alan Paterson, The Sacramento-
San Joaquin River Delta: The Evolution and Implementation
of Water Policy, An Historical Perspective, California
Water Resources Center, University of California, Davis,
Contribution No. 163, June 1977, p. 102. 
34. The Racanelli decision, United States of America et al v.
State Water Resources Control Board, 182 Cal. App. 3d 82;
227 Cal.Rptr.161 (Cal.App.1 Dist. 1986), was appealed to the
California Supreme Court, which refused to review the case
on September 18, 1986, thereby letting the appellate court
decision stand. The eight plaintiffs were: the Central Valley
East Side Project Irrigation Association (a precursor to the
Friant Water Users Authority), Kern County Water Agency,
South Delta Water Agency, San Joaquin County Flood
Control and Water Conservation District, the Contra Costa
County Water Agency, the United States Bureau of Reclamation,
and two Antioch-area private corporations, Fibreboard
and Crown Zellerbach. All page citations are to 182
Cal.App.3d 82 and following pagination. 
35. Ibid., p. 118. 
36. Racanelli merely noted it would be “too cumbersome and
impractical to accomplish the mandated periodic revisions of
water quality control plans” since reallocating water rights is
the only enforcement mechanism available to the Board for
administering its water quality standards and protecting
beneficial uses under the Clean Water Act. Ibid., 119. 
37. Ibid., p. 140, 141. 
38. See also Tim Stroshane, “A History of the Monterey
Agreement: Glimpsing the Future,” SPILLWAY v1n2, Winter
2000, p. 4. 
39. Racanelli decision, op. cit., note 34, p. 147.

No comments:

Post a Comment